蒙汉女性人力资本代际传递比较研究
详细信息    本馆镜像全文|  推荐本文 |  |   获取CNKI官网全文
摘要
当前我国正处于社会转型时期,社会结构板结、贫富差距拉大、“二代”等现象的出现正在拷问着我国社会公平机制,这些问题的症结所在均与人力资本的代际传递息息相关。党的十八届三中全会《关于全面深化改革若干重大问题的决定》成为我国新时期推进改革促进发展的指导性文件,提出了“社会、政治、经济、文化、生态”五位一体的协调发展方略,并将社会公平发展列为一项突出的目标,众多举措都是围绕着社会公平机制构建而推出的,而其中的核心是如何推进教育公平问题。
     从对国内外人力资本代际传递理论的文献梳理中发现,大量的实证研究是在欧美发达国家的数据背景下展开的,针对发展中国家的研究较少,更少见以亚洲为背景的研究,我国的人力资本代际传递问题的研究应该具有更加典型的意义。我国国内的研究中更多的是将人力资本代际传递做为收入、贫困等代际传递问题的一个解释变量,较少真正关注人力资本代际传递本身的机制、途径与影响因素,而且比较研究也缺乏广度和深度。本研究选取性别与民族相交叉的视角探讨人力资本的代际传递问题,必将给这一领域的研究带来新的启示,并试图探索推进教育公平、促进代际和谐发展的有效路径。
     本文的基本逻辑结构是理论基础→机制分析→实证分析→政策开发。在相关理论研究的基础上,深入解析了人力资本代际传递的机制、动机、经济学模型描述以及女性人力资本代际传递的途径,厘清了一些人力资本代际传递的理论问题。人力资本代际传递可以在宏观层面上来进行,其微观传递机制则是在家庭层面来完成的。以家庭为基础所发生的人力资本代际传递行为的动机是复杂的,家庭总效用最大只有在代际互利模式下才能产生,这种互利的出发点或根本动机应该是利他主义驱动的。在引入社会性别视角来审视人力资本代际传递的动机与模式时,男性(父亲)的动机更倾向于以利己为出发点的互利模式,而女性(母亲)则更倾向于利他为出发点的互利模式或者纯粹的利他动机。女性人力资本的代际传递途径包括直接途径和间接途径。直接途径主要通过遗传、家庭教育以及女性直接从事教育工作等通道完成的;间接途径则是女性人力资本以生育率、收入和时间为介质完成了向下一代的传递。
     以人力资本代际传递的宏观机制为基础,以我国历次人口普查数据为依据,测算了我国蒙汉族两个群体的人力资本存量,构造了三个相互交叉的代际关系观察人力资本代际传递增值率的变化。研究发现我国的人力资本积累是不均衡的,性别之间、民族之间、城乡之间人力资本存量存在着结构性差异,并保持着代际间的一致性,而城乡差异在代际间的缩减幅度明显滞后于民族本身的差异和性别差异,说明城乡人力资本存量结构性失衡具有更顽强的惯性。女性人力资本代际传递增值率明显高于男性人力资本代际传递增值率,提升女性人力资本可以带来更大的代际增值效益。
     以人力资本代际传递的微观机制为基础,以调研数据为依据,对蒙汉女性人力资本代际传递依存度进行了实证分析。研究认为:女性人力资本的代际传递总体效应要高于男性人力资本的代际传递效应,并且在民族间存在一定的差异性;城乡差距因素是影响子代人力资本获得的最显著的因素,农村牧区家庭子女的受教育程度全面处于劣势;汉族的性别不平等现象要比蒙古族严重,女性受教育程度处于劣势;做为少数民族这一特征仍会对子代的人力资本获得有微弱的负效应,而这种负效应伴随着城乡差距的巨大影响同步存在。母亲人力资本的代际传递效应存在着性别差异和城乡差异,其间蒙汉族之间的表现并不完全相同。
     基于本研究的机制分析与实证分析,可以证明在当前我国的现实条件下,个体的受教育程度在一定程度上出现了对家庭背景因素等先赋条件的依赖,人力资本获得代际固化现象比较明显,这在一定程度上应该归因于家庭背景因素对个体受教育机会的干预,造成了教育机会不平等,最终影响了个体人力资本获得的公平性。制度安排会显著影响人力资本的代际流动的模式,最为公平的人力资本代际流动模式——基于能力的自由竞争模式不具备其存在的基本前提,任由最不公平的人力资本代际流动模式——基于机会不平等的承继模式发展下去,将会严重影响社会公平机制的建立,政策制定可以干预到个体受教育机会,从而减弱家庭背景等先赋因素对教育机会不平等的决定作用,这就是更为合理的人力资本代际流动模式——政策干预下的自由竞争模式。针对蒙汉女性人力资本代际传递比较分析中的差异性,本研究认为重视并加大汉族女性人力资本投资、推进民族地区城乡教育一体化、建立能力导向的教育筛选制度等措施将有助于推进教育公平,促进代际和谐发展。
Currently, our country is in the period of social transformation, the social structure is hardened, the gap between rich and poor is widening, the emergence of the phenomenon such as "second generation" is about social justice mechanism in our country, the crux of these problems is closely related with the intergenerational transmission of human capital. At the Third Plenary Session of the18th Central Committee of the Communist,"Certain major issue decision about comprehensively deepen reform" has been introduced, and became the guidance documents of promoting reform and development during the new period of our country, it put forward a coordinated development strategy integrated social, political, economic, cultural and ecological, and to develop social justice as a prominent goal, many measures are all about building social justice mechanism, which is the core of education fairness.
     From the searching literature review of intergenerational transmission of human capital theory at home and abroad, we found that a large number of empirical studies is based on the data of developed countries in Europe and America, there is not much study on developing countries, research in Asia as the background is even less. Intergenerational transmission of human capital in China should have more typical significance. Our domestic studies are likely to view intergenerational transmission of human capital as an explanation variable of intergenerational transmission of problems such as poverty, income, focusing less on real mechanism, motivation, the influence factors, the transfer way of the intergenerational transmission of human capital itself. In addition, comparative studies is also lack of breadth and depth. This research takes the perspective of gender and ethnic crossover problem of intergenerational transmission of human capital will bring new enlightenment to the research of this field, and tries to explore the promotion education fairness, to explore the effective path to promote intergenerational harmonious development.
     In this paper, the basic logical structure is the theoretical basis to mechanism analysis, to empirical analysis, to policy development. Firstly, it is necessary to clarify some problems of intergenerational transmission of human capital theory. Intergenerational transmission of human capital can be done on a macro level, the micro transmission mechanism is accomplished at the family level. The motivation of intergenerational transmission of human capital on the basis of the family is complicated, family total utility maximum only can be made basing on the mode of intergenerational mutual benefits, the starting point of the mutually beneficial or fundamental motive should be driven by altruism. The introduction of a gender perspective to look at the motives of intergenerational transmission of human capital and mode, the motivation of male (father) is more inclined to benefit as the starting point of mutually beneficial pattern, while women (mother) were more likely to concessionary as the starting point of mutually beneficial mode or purely altruistic motives. The intergenerational transmission of female human capital including direct way and indirect way. Direct way means mainly through heredity, family education and women engaged in education work such as channel. Indirect way means that female human capital depends on some medium to pass to the next generation, such as fertility rates, income, and time.
     Based on the macro mechanism of intergenerational transmission of human capital, on the basis of our country all previous census data, and evaluate the human capital stock of the two nationality groups of the Han and the Mongolian in our country, structure the relationship between the three overlapping generations then observe the changes of intergenerational transmission value-added rate of human capital. The study found that the human capital accumulation is not balanced in our country, significant structural differences of human capital stock exist in different gender, nationality, and the urban and rural, and keep the consistency between generations. Furthermore, the differences between urban and rural from one generation to the contraction obviously lags behind the ethnic and gender differences of itself, illustrates structural imbalances in urban and rural human capital has the more strong inertia. Women intergenerational transmission of human capital value-added rate is significantly higher than male intergenerational transmission of human capital, hence improve female human capital will lead to greater intergenerational value-added benefits.
     On the basis of survey data, has carried on the empirical analysis about intergenerational transmission of female human capital between Han and Mongolian at the micro family level. The main results:1) the overall effect of intergenerational transmission of female human capital is higher than that of male human capital intergenerational transfer effect, but there exists certain differences between ethnic groups;2) the gap between urban and rural factor is the most significant factor affecting human capital for offspring, rural and parish family children's level of education at a disadvantage;3) The gender inequality in Han is more serious than Mongolian, women's level of education at a disadvantage;4) The feature as a minority will still be slightly negative effects for the offspring to gain human capital, and the negative effects associated with the impact of the gap between urban and rural areas exist simultaneously.5) There exist gender differences and urban and rural differences in the intergenerational transfer effect of mother human capital of human capital.
     Based on mechanism analysis and empirical analysis of this research, it is proved that under our current conditions, the educational level of individual relies to a certain extent on the heredity situations, like family background. What's more, it is proved that human capital are easily affected and stereotyped by former generations, which can be attributed to the intervention of the influence of family background on the chances of individual's education, and as a result, the unfairness of educational opportunity appears and eventually has an effect on the fairness of individual's human capital. System arrangement has significant influence on the mode of the intergenerational mobility of human capital, under the realistic condition restriction of the current our country, the most fair intergenerational mobility of human capital model, based on the ability of free competition pattern, does not have the basic premise of its existence, but leaving the most unfair intergenerational mobility of human capital model, based on the inheritance patterns of inequality of opportunity, will seriously affect the establishment of the mechanism of social justice, the government can appropriate powerful policy intervention to individual education opportunities, and decreases ascribed factors such as family background of the mind in determining how unequal education, which is a more reasonable human capital intergenerational mobility models-free competition under the policy intervention. According to the differences in the comparative analysis of intergenerational transmission of female human capital both of Han and Mongolian, this study thought some policies should be taken to promote education fair and intergenerational harmonious development, which are attaches importance to and strengthen Han nationality female human capital investment, promote the integration of urban and rural education in national regions, establishing ability oriented education system of screening.
引文
① http://news.ifeng.com/mainland/detail_2013_11/05/30953175_0.shtml
    [1]Eide E.R. and Showalter M.H., Factors affecting the transmission of earnings across Generations:A quintile regression approach, The Journal of Human Resources. 1999,34 (2):253-267.
    [2]贝克尔著,梁小民译.人力资本[M].北京:北京大学出版社,1987:1.
    [3]池丽萍,俞国良.教育成就代际传递的机制:资本和沟通的视角[J].教育研究,2011(9):22-28.
    [4]Becker & Tomes, human capital and the rise and falls of family, Journal of labor Economics.1986,4 (3):1-39.
    [5]Hannum, Emily and Yu Xie. Ethnic Stratification in Northwest China:Occupational Differences between Han Chinese and National Minorities in Xinjiang,1982-1990. Demography.1998,35(3).
    [6]万秀兰.美国少数民族高等教育问题的表现、原因及对策[J].比较教育研究,2002(8):34-38.
    [7]洪岩壁.族群与教育不平等:我国西部少数民族教育获得的一项实证研究[J].社会,2010(2):45-73.
    [8]Becker G.S. A Treatise on the Family. Cambridge, Harvard University Press, Massachusetts.1991.
    [9]Cox D. Motives for private income transfers, Journal of Political Economy.1987,95: 508-546.
    [10]Kotlikoff, Morris. How much care do the aged receive from their children in the economics of aging, Wise (ed.), Chicago, University of Chicago Press.1989.
    [11]Altonji, Hayashi & Kotlikoff. Is the extended family altruistically linked? Direct tests using micro data. American Economic Review.1992,82:1177-1198.
    [12]Altonji, Hayashi & Kotlikoff. Parental altruism and inter vivos transfers:Theory and evidence. Journal of Political Economy.1997,105:1121-1166.
    [13]Cigno, Giannelli & Rosati. Voluntary transfers among Italian households: Altruistic and non-altruistic explanations. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics.1998,9:435-451.
    [14]Lucas R.E.B., and O. Stark. Motivations to remit:Evidence from Botswana. Journal of Political Economy.1985,93:901-18.
    [15]Heckman, Vytlacil. Identifying the role of cognitive ability in explaining the level of and change in the return to schooling. Review Economic Statistics.2001, 83(1):1-12.
    [16]Taubman P.. The determinants of earnings:genetics, family, and other environments:a study of white male twins. American Economic Review.1976, 66(5):858-870.
    [17]Plug E., Vijverberg W.. Schooling, family background, and adoption:is it nature or is it nurture. Journal of Political Economy.2003,111(3):611-641.
    [18]Bjorklund, Lindahl & Plug. Intergenerational effects in Sweden:what can we learn from adoption data?. IZA Discussion Papers 1194, Institute for the Study of Labor.2004.
    [19]Sacerdote, B.. How large are the effects from changes in family environment? A study of Korean-American adoptees. Q J Econ.2007,122(1):119-157.
    [20]Brown, McIntosh &Taylor. Following in your parents'footsteps? Empirical analysis of matched parent-offspring test scores. IZA Discussion Paper No.3986. 2009.
    [21]Silke Anger, Guido Heineck. Do smart parents raise smart children? The intergenerational transmission of cognitive abilities. Journal of Population Economics.2010,23:1255-1282.
    [22]Black, Devereux & Salvanes. Like father, like son? Anote on the intergenerational transmission of IQ scores. Economics Letters.2009,105(1):138-140.
    [23]Leibowitz, A.. Home Investments in Children. Journal of Political Economy.1974, 82(2):111-131.
    [24]Leibowitz, A.. Parental inputs and children's achievement. Journal of Human Resources.1977,12(2):243-251.
    [25]Han, Waldfogel & Brooks-Gunn. The effects of early maternal employment on later cognitive and behavioral outcomes. Journal of Marriage and the Family.2001, 63(2):336-354.
    [26]J. Ignacio Gimenez-Nadal. Parents'education as determinant of time transfers to children:an intergenerational transfer approach. European Economic Association & Econometric Society 2011 Parallel Meetings,25-29 August 2011, Oslo.
    [27]Helmuth Cremer, Pierre Pestieau. Intergenerational Transfer of Human Capital and Optimal Education Policy. Journal of Public Economic Theory.2006,8(4): 529-545.
    [28]James McIntosh, Martin D. Munk. Scholastic ability vs family background in educational success:evidence from Danish sample survey data. Journal of Population Economics.2007,20:101-120.
    [29]James McIntosh. Educational mobility in Canada:results from the 2001 general social survey. Empirical Economics.2010,38:457-470.
    [30]Regina T. Riphahn, Florian Schieferdecker. The transition to tertiary education and parental background over time. Journal of Population Economics.2012,25:635 -675.
    [31]Guryan, Jonathan, Erik Hurst, and Melissa Kearney. Parental Education and Parental Time with Children. Journal of Economic Perspectives.2008,22 (3): 23-46.
    [32]Sharada Weir. Intergenerational transfers of human capital:evidence on two types of education externalities. Centre for the Study of African Economies WPS/2000.15, Oxford.2000.
    [33]Plug, E.. Estimating the effect of mother's schooling on children's education using a sample of adoptees. American Economic Review.2004,94(1):358-368.
    [34]Bjorklund, Lindahl & Plug. The origins of intergenerational associations:lessons from Swedish data. Q J Econ..2006,121(3):999-1028.
    [35]Chiara Pronzato. An examination of paternal and maternal intergenerational transmission of schooling. Journal of Population Economics.2010,25:591-608.
    [36]Currie Janet and Enrico Moretti. Mother's Education and the Intergenerational Transmission of Human Capital:Evidence from College Openings and Longitudinal Data. Quarterly Journal of Economics.2003,4:1495-1532.
    [37]Coleman J. S.. Social capital in the creation of human capital", American Journal of Sociology.1988,94:S95-S120.
    [38]Borjas George J.. Ethnic capital and intergenerational mobility. Quarterly Journal of Economics.1992,107(1):123-150.
    [39]Nielsen, R., Tarpy, D. R. and Reeve, H. K.. Estimating the effective paternity numbdetecter in social insects and the effective number of alleles in a population. Molecular Ecology 2003,12:3157-3164.
    [40]Bradley, S. and A. N. Nguyen. The School-to-Work Transition. International Handbook of Education Economics.2004, Cheltenham:484-521.
    [41]Alain-Desire Nimubona, Desire Vencatachellum. Intergenerational education mobility of black and white South Africans. Journal of Population Economics. 2007,20:149-182.
    [42]Gang Zimmermann. Is child like parent?:educational attainment and ethnic origin. Journal of Human Resources.2000,35(3):550-569.
    [43]Card, DiNardo & Estes. The more things change:immigrants and the children of immigrants in the 1940s, the 1970s, and the 1990s. In:Borjas GC (ed) Issues in the economics of immigration. University of Chicago Press, Chicago.2000, pp 227-269.
    [44]Colding B.. A dynamic analysis of educational progression of children of emigrants. Labour Economics.2006,13(4):479-492.
    [45]Philipp Bauer & Regina T. Riphahn. Education and its intergenerational transmission:country of origin-specific evidence for natives and immigrants from Switzerland. Portuguese Economic Journal.2006,5:89-110.
    [46]Slobodan Djajic. Assimilation of immigrants:Implications for human capital accumulation of the second generation. Journal of Population Economics. 2003,16:831-845.
    [47]David McKenzie, Hillel Rapoport. Can migration reduce educational attainment? Evidence from Mexico. Journal of Population Economics.2011,24:1331-1358.
    [48]Black, Devereux & Salvanes. Why the apple doesn't fall far:understanding intergenerational transmission of human capital. American Economic Review. 2005,95(1):437-449.
    [49]Mihails Hazans, Ija Trapeznikova & Olga Rastrigina. Ethnic and parental effects on schooling outcomes before and during the transition:evidence from the Baltic countries. Journal of Population Economics.2008,21:719-749.
    [50]Helmuth Cremer, Pierre Pestieau. Intergenerational Transfer of Human Capital and Optimal Education Policy. Journal of Public Economic Theory.2006,8(4):529-545.
    [51]Becker, G. S..'Bribe'third world parents to keep their kids in school. Business Week(Industrial/technology edition). New York:November 22,1999. Iss.3656; pg. 15.
    [52]钟笑寒.代际转移机制研究[J].数量经济技术经济研究,1998(3):48-50.
    [53]李煜.代际流动的模式:理论理想型与中国现实[J].社会,2009(6):60-81.
    [54]李春玲.社会政治变迁与教育机会不平等——家庭背景及制度因素对教育获得的影响(1940-2001)[J].中国社会科学,2003(3):86-98.
    [55]刘志国,范亚静.教育的代际流动性影响因素分析[J].教育科学,2013(2):1-5.
    [56]郭丛斌,闵维方.家庭经济和文化资本对子女教育机会获得的影响[J].高等教育研究,2006(11):24-31.
    [57]郭丛斌,闵维方.教育:创设合理的代际流动机制——结构方程模型在教育与代际流动关系研究中的应用[J].教育研究,2009(10):5-12.
    [58]齐亚强,牛建林.教育的再生产:代际传承与变迁[J].中国人民大学教育学刊,2012(1):37-55.
    [59]马新.教育公平对切断贫困代际传递的作用[J].现代教育管理,2009(1):19-22.
    [60]林森,单莉莉.教育机会平等与低收入阶层代际延续关系分析[J].湖湘论坛,2010(5):109-112.
    [61]胡颖森.我国低收入家庭子女高等教育投资收益问题研究[J].求索,2012(7):256-257.
    [62]李晓明.我国山区少数民族农民贫困代际传递的基本特征[J].内蒙古社会科学,2005(11):150-152.
    [63]张锦华.我国欠发达地区教育公共投资低发展陷阱研究——基于代际传递的实证分析[J].财经研究,2008(7):98-108.
    [64]王爱君.女性贫困、代际传递与和谐增长[J].财经科学,2009(6):47-54.
    [65]林上洪.母亲受教育状况对代际流动的影响——基于清代科举人物朱卷履历的分析[J].教育与考试,2012(5):41-46.
    [66]张景美.我国女性社会流动与成人教育[J].西北成人教育学报,2004(2):17-20.
    [67]石中英.教育公平的主要内涵与社会意义[J].中国教育学刊,2008(03):1-27.
    [68]亚当·斯密.财富的性质和原因的研究(上卷)[M].北京:商务印书馆,1997:13-14.
    [69]梁洪学.“经济人”假定理论的演进与发展——兼评“经济人”假定的客观性[J].江汉论坛,2003(7):41-45.
    [70]西蒙.管理行为[M].北京:北京经济学院出版社,1988:79.
    [71]费孝通.家庭结构变动中的老年赡养问题:再论中国家庭结构的变动[J].北京大学学报(哲学社会科学版),1983(3):6-15.
    [72]福尔迈著,舒远招译.进化认识论[M].武汉:武汉大学出版社,1994:136-137.
    [73]Silke Anger & Guido Heineck. Do smart parents raise smart children? The intergenerational transmission of cognitive abilities. J Popul Econ.2010, 23:1255-1282.
    [74]Kao G, Rutherford L T. Does Social Capital Still Matter? Immigrant Minority Disadvantage in School-Specific Social Capitaland its Effects on Academic Achievement. Sociological Perspectives,2007, (50).
    [75]Ermisch J, Francesconi M.. Family matters:impacts of family background on educational attainment. Economica.2001,68(270):137-156.
    [76]Tenenbaum H R, Leaper C. Parent-Child Conversationsabout Science:The Cocialization of Gender Inequities?. Developmental Psychology.2003, (39).
    [77]池丽萍.亲子沟通的三层次模型:理论、工具及在小学生中的应用[J].心理发展与教育,2011(2):140-150.
    [78]Huntsinger C S, et al. Mathematics,Vocabulary,and Reading Development in Chinese American and European American Children Over the Primary School Years. Journal of Educational Psychology.2000, (92).
    [79]刘铮.人口现代化与优先发展教育[J].人口研究,1992(2):1-10.
    [80]钟年.女性家庭:社会历史和文化心理的追问[J].武汉大学学报(哲学社会科 学版),2008(2):263-269.
    [81]邓宏碧主编.中国少数民族人口政策研究[M].重庆:重庆出版社,1998:111.
    [82]易翠枝,赵小仕.婚姻市场的教育匹配与分层及其经济影响[J].商业时代,2007(7):12-13+73.
    [83]世界银行:1993年世界发展报告。
    [84]蔡昉等.依靠深化教育缓解就业压力[J].理论视野,2009(5):30-33.
    [85]郭凤鸣.中国城镇劳动力市场上性别工资差异的经验研究[D].长春:吉林大学,2011年。
    [86]雷晓燕.中老年女性劳动供给及代际转移在子女间的差异[J].人口与经济,2009(6):7-13.
    [87]王德劲.我国人力资本测算及其应用研究[D].成都:西南财经大学,2008年。
    [88]朱翊敏,钟庆才.广东省经济增长中人力资本贡献的实证分析[J].中国工业经济,2002(12):73-80.
    [89]徐迎春等.中国人力资本与经济增长关系的实证研究[J].山东行政学院山东省经济管理干部学院学报,2005(5)增刊:136-144.
    [90]赖明勇,袁媛.国际技术外溢及人力资本一个经验研究[J].科研管理,2005(4):62-67.
    [91]宋光辉.不同文化程度人口对我国经济增长的贡献——我国经济增长与教育关系的一种实证分析(1981-2000年)[J].财经科学,2003(1):75-81.
    [92]胡鞍钢.从人口大国到人力资本大国:1980-2000年[J].中国人口科学,2002(5):3-12.
    [93]王金营.西部地区人力资本在经济增长中的作用核算[J].中国人口科学,2005(3):63-68.
    [94]胡永远.人力资本与经济增长:一个协整分析[J].科技管理研究,2005(4):88-90.
    [95]田雪源.中国民族人口(一)[M].北京:中国人口出版社,2002:133.
    [96]朋·乌恩主编.蒙古族传统美德[M].呼和浩特:远方出版社,2002:242,243.
    [97]Hannum, Emily. Educational Stratification by Ethnicity in China:Enrollment and Attainment in the Early Reform Years. Demography.2002,39 (1).
    [98]李强.社会分层与贫富差别[M].厦门:鹭江出版社,2009:77-78.
    [99]王树新.社会变革与代际关系研究[M].北京:首都经贸大学出版社,2004:1-2.
    [100]Chiswick B.R.. Differences in education and earnings across racial and ethnic groups:tastes, discrimination, and investments in child quality. Q J Econ.1988, 103(3):571-597.
    [101]Belzil C,Hansen J.. Structural estimates of the intergenerational education correlation. J Appl Econ.2003,18(6):679-696.
    [102]戴成萍.蒙古族生育文化.载于郑玉顺主编.第三届妇女发展与进步国际学术研讨会论文集[C].北京:民族出版社,2006:298.
    [103]Blau, Peter. M. and O. D. Duncan. The American Occupational Structure. NY: Wiley.1967.
    [104]Torche,Florencia.2005. Unequal butFluid:SocialMobility in Chile in Comparative Perspective. American Sociological Review 70:422-50.
    [105]Bourdieu, Pierre. The School as A Conservative Force:Scholastic and Cultural Inequalities. In Contemporary Research in the Sociology of Education, edited by J.Eggleston. London:Methuen.1974.
    [106]周谨平.机会平等与分配正义[M].北京:人民出版社,2009:P143.
    [107]张抗私.就业性别歧视与人力资本投资倾向的交互作用分析[J].浙江大学学报(人文社会科学版),2009(5):103-111.
    [108]周玉.教育与农村女性代际流动—以文化再生产理论为分析框架[J].福建论坛(人文社会科学版),2006(11):139-142.
    [109]张旺.城乡教育一体化:教育公平的时代诉求[J].教育研究,2012(8):13-18.
    [110]凡勇昆,邬志辉.论我国新农村建设与农村教育布局调整[J].教育研究,2013(7):28-36.
    [111]邬志辉,史宁中.农村学校布局调整的十年走势与政策议题[J].教育研究,2011(7):22-30.
    [112]郭彩琴,顾志平.城乡教育一体化的困境与应对措施[J].人民教育,2010(20):2-5.
    [113]褚宏启.城乡教育一体化:体系重构与制度创新——中国教育二元结构及其破解[J].教育研究,2009(11):3-10+26.
    [114]庄万禄,来仪.民族地区教育现状与对策研究——以云南、贵州、四川三省为例[J].西南民族学院学报(哲学社会科学版),2002(5):21-31.
    [115]Ptricia M.Broadfoot, Education, Assessment and Society, A Socioloical Analysis, Open University Press,1996:9-16转引自:周作宇.教育、社会分层与社会流动[J].北京师范大学学报(人文社会科学版),2001(5):90.
    [116]刘精明.教育选择方式及其后果[J].中国人民大学学报,2004(1):67.
    [117]李雪岩等.高考加分政策与青年入学机会公平评析[J].当代青年研究,2010(3):28-33.
    [118]斯琴格日乐.教育公平视角下少数民族高考倾斜政策的现实冲突与改进对策[J].中国青年研究,2013(2):15-18+78.